Page Created:
        August 23, 2005
Last updated:
        March 25, 2012

Tax Simplification: Just Get Rid of 89 Million Unnecessary Returns


by Jay Starkman, CPA

 *  *  *


"The individual income tax is our fiscal beast of burden."
                -- Randolph E. Paul1
IRS statistics reveal that just 9 percent of individual income tax revenue is raised from 68 percent of the returns filed with the IRS -- 89 million of the 130 million returns processed . That means that an inordinate amount of resources are devoted to collecting $72 billion of tax. The remaining 32 percent of the tax returns yield $725 billion. The 68 percent includes all single persons earning up to a little over $35,000 annually and all married couples earning up to a little over $60,000.

Table 1. 2002 IRS Statistics of Income Summary Estimate of Taxes
              Raised by Incomes Not Exceeding the 15 Percent
                Tax Bracket (tax dollars in thousands)



Single

Married
Joint
Head of Household and Other

Total
Gross income taxed at 15 percent or less
$35,650

$60,550

$47,350

Tax collections for taxpayers not exceeding the 15 percent bracket*
$37,195,692

$23,812,874

$11,455,869

$72,464,435
Total Tax collections, all incomes
$184,587,392 $565,077,480 $47,321,396 $796,986,268
Percentage of total tax collections, from those in 15 percent bracket or less

20%

4%

24%

9%

Number of Returns, for taxpayers not exceeding the 15 percent bracket
Nontaxable
15,108,925 9,623,006 12,368,747 37,100,678
Taxable
28,090,616 17,527,845 6,205,858 51,824,319
Total
43,199,541 27,150,851 18,574,605 88,924,997
Total Returns, all incomes
57,199,788 51,302,090 18,574,605 130,076,444
Percentage of returns up to the 15 percent bracket

76%

53%

86%

68%
Source: Author's calculations based on data from IRS Statistics of Income 2002 (Winter 2005), "Table 1.2  --  2002, Individual Income Tax, All Returns: Adjusted Gross Income, Exemptions, Deductions, and Tax Items, by Size of Adjusted Gross Income and by Marital Status."

The author claims no expertise in the black art of revenue estimating. With more detailed statistics these estimates, especially the married-joint calculation, could be better delineated. For purposes of this article, the estimates are presented as reasonable evidence to bolster the contention that the vast majority of income tax returns raise little revenue.
 * Income only for those whose adjusted gross income is less than $35,600/$47,350/$60,550 is considered. That is the total of taxable income comprising the 15 percent bracket plus the standard deduction and personal exemption. Income from capital gains above those amounts, which is taxed at 15 percent, is excluded. Dependent exemptions are excluded. These taxes reflect $1.1 billion of EITC that is included in the IRS statistics to the extent that its application does not reduce income tax before credits below zero. Child credits are included to the same extent, but the amount of credit cannot be determined.

The last time the United States really simplified the income tax was in 1872, when the Civil War income tax was repealed. Every tax act since has added complexity. Laws purporting to simplify include new elections, computations, deductions, credits, or phase-ins. Targeted simplification, like simplifying the definition of dependent or the proposed rationalization of the myriad education incentives, merely mop up the mess created by prior tax bills, clearing the deck for future complications.

Recently, there have been two articles proposing real simplification: "100 Million Unnecessary Returns" by Michael Graetz (Yale University)2 and "44 Million Will File Tax Returns But Pay Nothing" by Scott Hodge (the Tax Foundation).3 The IRS receives 130 million Forms 1040 annually. True simplification would reduce tax filings by tens of millions.

Does fairness require that everyone participate in the income tax for the upkeep of government? Even when compliance costs make it uneconomical? How did the income tax become a tax on the masses?

My objectives in this article are to explain the historical reasons that we have no national sales tax and how that contributed to income tax complexity, and to show that real simplification requires exempting a majority of the population from the income tax.

How Income Tax Became a Mass Tax

Initially, the income tax was strictly a revenue measure. Once the Civil War debt was repaid, that revenue was no longer needed, so the 1862-1872 income tax was repealed. For the next 40 years, the government was financed through excises and high tariffs -- consumption taxes.

The poor spent every penny, so they bore a heavy burden of consumption taxes. The wealthy, to the extent they saved or spent funds on services or nonimports, paid a lighter tax as a percentage of income. That made taxation regressive. Adding some progressivity to the nation's tax system was the impetus behind the 1894 income tax. It was a 2 percent tax on incomes exceeding $4,000.

Congress debated whether income tax should be used for progressivity or whether everyone should participate. Rep. William Bourke Cockran of New York, reputed to be the best Democratic orator in the House, made a convincing argument against an income tax targeting only the rich:
    You have not attempted to tax the people, but you have attempted to tax the incomes of 85,000 of them. You have undertaken to set aside a class on which alone this tax is to fall, and to degrade the balance of the people to a plane of inferior importance. . . . He who is relieved from taxation, who is exempt from his share in one single burden of government, forfeits to that extent the grounds upon which his right to control the Government is based.4
Rep. William Jennings Bryan retorted eloquently:
    Why, sir, the gentleman from New York said that the poor are opposed to this tax because they do not want to be deprived of participation in it, and that taxation instead of being a sign of servitude is a badge of freedom. If taxation is a badge of freedom, let me assure my friend that the poor people of this country are covered all over with the insignia of freemen.5
The 1894 tax passed, but was soon declared unconstitutional. Following ratification of the 16th Amendment, the 1913 income tax had the same goal, featuring a $3,000 ($4,000 married) exemption with graduated rates from 1 percent to 7 percent to enhance progressivity. To finance World War I, rates rose all the way to 77 percent, but the exemption remained high enough to exempt most of the population. See Table 2.

In a misguided attempt to balance the budget in 1932, House Speaker John Nance Garner reached agreement with Treasury Secretary Ogden Mills and Ways and Means Committee Chair Charles Crisp to support a 2.25 percent national sales tax on everything except food and cheaper clothing. Almost every national political leader from the president to the leaders of both houses of Congress supported the sales tax. So did Bernard Baruch and William Randolph Hearst. To disguise the nature of the tax, it would be called a "manufacturer's tax."

Led by Reps. Fiorello LaGuardia, who later became mayor of New York City, and Robert Doughton, who later became chair of the Ways and Means Committee, members rebelled against their House leaders. The tax was opposed by the American Federation of Labor, four farm groups, retailers, and wholesalers. There were mass meetings throughout the country to protest the tax. It was overwhelmingly defeated.

There was a general feeling that sales tax was the domain of the states, and that the federal government should not endeavor to enact a sales tax because it would compete with the states' ability to raise revenue. To cover the revenue shortfall, the Revenue Act of 1932 boosted income tax and estate tax rates.

In a lame duck session in December 1932, President Herbert Hoover again asked Congress to enact the sales tax and Garner promised to allow the bill to reach the House floor. Thereupon, President-elect Franklin Delano Roosevelt announced that he opposed a federal sales tax. From his experience as New York's governor, Roosevelt decided it was best that federal and state governments not levy taxes on the same source and that a general sales tax should be the exclusive domain of the states. The federal sales tax proposal was dead.6

World War II brought not only high rates but decreases in the personal exemption. Wage withholding was introduced to avoid a collection nightmare. The income tax was transformed from an elite tax to a mass tax. Why?

The personal exemption was significantly lowered in 1940 and again in 1941 as part of a "preparedness" campaign. The Roosevelt administration in 1942 contemplated financing for World War II through higher income tax rates. Republicans proposed an alternative: A sales tax for the purpose of having those with low incomes contribute to the treasury. Had Roosevelt not opposed a federal sales tax, we would have one today. Instead, Treasury Secretary Henry Morgenthau made a counterproposal to lower the personal exemption to $624. It was uneconomical to have income tax reach such small incomes, but it was sold as a compromise to defeat the sales tax initiative.7

Table 2. Personal Exemption 1913-1969

Exemption Single
Married
Dependents
1913-1916
$3,000
$4,000
$-0-
1917-1920
$1,000
$2,000
$200
1921-1924
$1,000 $2,500 $400
1925-1931
$1,500 $3,500 $400
1932-1939
$1,000 $2,500 $400
1940
$800
$2,000 $400
1941
$750 $1,500 $400
1942-1943
$624 $1,248 $312
1944-1947
$500 $1,000 $500
1948-1969
$600 $1,200 $600
Source: IRS Statistics of Income, Appendix to Selected Historical and Other Data Tables, Table A. -- U.S. Individual Income Tax: Personal Exemptions and and Highest Brackets Tax Rates, and Tax Base for Regular Tax, Tax Years 1913-2003 (except 1942-1943 taken from Randolph Paul, Taxation in the United States (Boston: Little, Brown, and Company, 1954), p. 348). See http://www.irs.gov/pub/irs-soi/03inta.xls .

The personal exemption reached a nadir of $500 in 1944, but that was enacted in conjunction with a new standard deduction and with an increase in the dependent exemption. Those 1944 changes dropped 12 million low-income people from the tax rolls. The Roosevelt administration recognized that collecting $161 million from taxpayers near the bottom endangered collection of $17 billion from 50 million other taxpayers.8

President Harry Truman cited fear of inflation and later financing for the Korean War as reasons for not lowering rates or raising exemptions. There was some modest relief in 1947, when rates were lowered slightly and the personal exemption was raised to $600.

President Dwight Eisenhower made overhaul of the Internal Revenue Code in 1954 the centerpiece of his tax policy. Its major individual tax policy was recodification of the World War II tax policy, making low-income individuals liable for income tax. Eisenhower echoed 19th century philosophy when he threatened to veto any bill that included an increase in exemptions, declaring:
    When the time comes to cut income taxes still more, let's cut them. But I do not believe that the way to do it is to excuse millions of taxpayers from paying any income tax at all . . . every real American is proud to carry his share of any burden. . . . I simply do not believe for one second that anyone privileged to live in this country wants someone else to pay his fair and just share of the cost of his Government.9
Complexity as Tax Relief

Alternate methods were created to supplement the personal exemption. The standard deduction, introduced as a 10 percent deduction ($1,000 maximum) from adjusted gross income in 1944, was converted into a fixed deduction after 1976. The refundable earned income tax credit is essentially a subsidy on the minimum wage. The child tax credit is a proxy for an increased dependent exemption and partial relief from FICA/Self-Employment tax.

The exemptions and standard deduction excused about half of all families from tax after World War II. Inflation, rising real incomes, bracket creep, and failure to adequately increase the exemption have now made the income tax almost universal. Median income for a family of four in 1948 was $3,468. With a $2,400 exemption and $347 standard deduction, only $721 was taxable (if they didn't itemize) -- just 20 percent of income was subject to tax. In 2001 that family earned $63,278 and, after $11,600 of exemptions and a $7,600 standard deduction, $44,078 was taxable -- 70 percent subject to tax. Today's tax reaches income levels far below those deemed fair or efficient under Roosevelt or Truman, and we're taxing a huge chunk of it for relatively little revenue!10

The Government Accountability Office singles out fraudulent EITC as a "high-risk" area. The IRS estimates that deliberate and inadvertent EITC noncompliance cost between $8.5 billion and $9.9 billion in 1999.11 As soon as an EITC-eligible individual gets his W-2 "refund ticket," he rushes to the tax preparer and the IRS receives a return in January. W-2s needn't be filed with the Social Security Administration (SSA) until February 28 (March 31 if filed electronically) and a 30-day extension is available. There is some further delay as the SSA processes and finally shares the information with the IRS. Except when security procedures have stopped a refund from being issued, it's only long after refunds have been cashed that the IRS can begin determining whether EITC refunds were proper. Protecting against fraudulent EITC diverts tremendous IRS resources that could quite profitably be directed toward high-income taxpayer compliance.

The EITC has fueled the growth of the commercial tax preparation industry. Few low-wage earners take advantage of the EITC advance payment process (Form W-5), so most have a large refund due at year- end. They are often in desperate need of money, and commercial preparers have developed sophisticated marketing presentations to sell those taxpayers refund anticipation loans with electronic filing. The refund which arrives three weeks earlier than it otherwise would costs those poor taxpayers 100 percent to 400 percent per annum interest.

The EITC and the child credit turn a simple tax return into one that is very complex. Unintelligible statutes force people to seek professional help. Can anyone translate or justify the following gobbledygook:
    The amount of the credit allowed under this subsection shall not be treated as a credit allowed under this subpart and shall reduce the amount of credit otherwise allowable under subsection (a) without regard to section 26(a). [IRC section 24(d)(1), child tax credit.]
Any wonder that the tax preparation industry pockets more than 10 percent of the EITC program on returns it prepares,12 probably the largest overhead for any federal welfare program? The fee abuses by the industry continue to be prosecuted by state attorneys general. Jackson Hewitt, the nation's second-largest preparer, reportedly earned 29 percent of its net revenues from facilitating tax refund loans.13

Some praise the Tax Reform Act of 1986 (TRA 86) as the model for a broad-based, revenue-neutral, low rate, efficient, and equitable tax system. As a tax return preparer, I found that it brought horrible complexity by dividing income into baskets of active income, passive income, and portfolio income. It introduced new discrepancies between book income and taxable income, and additional categories of alternative minimum taxable income. It added complex phaseouts of the benefit of the 15 percent bracket, itemized deductions, and personal exemptions. As it eliminated garden-variety real estate tax shelters, it added low-income housing credits, bringing a whole new generation of tax shelter promotion.

The real simplification in TRA 86 was elimination of preferential tax treatment for capital gains. But Congress was so confident that the repeal would be temporary that it failed to repeal the code sections distinguishing between long-term and short-term capital gains. The IRS was also skeptical and retained separate sections on Schedule D for tracking long-term and short-term capital transactions.

Regressivity

While tax rates have risen from the 28 percent TRA 86 rate, capital gains and dividend rates have been halved. The result is that some investment income is now taxed at a maximum 15 percent rate. Never before has this nation inverted taxation to favor the wealthy investment class over the working middle class. Even Richard Nixon gave a preference to wages with a maximum rate of 50 percent while other income was taxed at 70 percent.

In Bryan's time, tariffs made taxation regressive. Today it's Social Security taxes. The intergenerational promise of Social Security is financed through a tax on wage income under $90,000. Benefits are skewed so that those earning at the higher end toward $90,000 finance those earning at the lower end toward $3,000.

Fairness requires a review of the regressivity of FICA and self- employment taxes when considered in combination with the income tax. FICA began as a 2 percent levy. Today, it's a combined 15.3 percent on employees and employers. The government calculates a "reserve fund," the difference between cumulative receipts and benefits, but the reserve is used for current government spending. The mythical "reserve" cannot hide the regressive nature of a payroll tax whose surplus makes the federal budget deficit look much smaller.

A self-employed family that struggles to maintain a lower- middle-class lifestyle on $40,000 of income may owe no income tax, but pays nearly $6,000 in self-employment tax. For most people, the 15.3 percent burden on earned income far exceeds their income tax. What logic justifies a combined 30.3 percent marginal tax rate on those earning up to $60,000 annually, while higher incomes are taxed at a maximum of 35 percent, or 15 percent when income consists of capital gains and dividends? From a rate perspective, our tax on income has become regressive.14 (The January 1, 2013 Obama tax increases and ObamaCare 3.8 percent tax on gross income significantly raised taxes on capital gain and dividends to almost 25 percent for high earners, but makes a very strange progressivity curve between earned income and unearned income.)

Tax Fairness

Randolph Paul asserted that fairness in U.S. income taxation has been designed around ability to pay and rate progressivity. Conscious design should take advantage of the fact that lower-income individuals spend almost all of their income on consumption while higher-income individuals are the source for most savings and investment. That dichotomy between the consuming and saving segments provides an opportunity to simplify the income tax.

A consumption tax will reach all lower-income earnings, while an income tax is the only tax that will reach higher-income earnings. We don't need an income tax, certainly not a complex one, to tax the majority with lower incomes. Bryan's "insignia of freemen" alluded to consumption taxes in the form of tariffs and excises.

To collect $72 billion from the lower 68 percent, there are alternatives that don't require a tax return. How much is $72 billion? It's an 8 percent flat income withholding tax at source on the 68 percent. Or it's the equivalent of raising tax rates on the 32 percent by just 2 percent, but not as simple as exempting the first $60,000 of income. That 32 percent also pays tax on income below $60,000. I'm not advocating any particular method. Rather, I am merely demonstrating that a replacement for $72 billion in revenue is easily within reach.15

Rep. John Linder, R-Ga., proposed a regressive tax insidiously called the FairTax in 2003. It's a 30 percent national sales tax [23% according to supporters. Though a $100 item with 30% sales tax costs $130, that's 23% "tax inclusive:" $130-($130 x 23%) = $100. Thus $30 tax added to a $100 purchase is a 23% tax!] could replace income, payroll, estate and gift taxes. The practical effect would dramatically lower the tax on the wealthy and raise it on the poor and middle classes. The simple fact is that the majority spends everything they earn and would be fully taxed, while the wealthy could avoid the tax by saving, or spending abroad.16 Today, FairTax is still pending legislation going nowhere, sponsored by Rep. Rob Woodall (R-GA) and Sen. Saxby Chambliss (R-GA).

Michael Graetz proposes a new federal value added tax at a 10 percent to 15 percent rate, a $100,000 family income tax exemption ($50,000 single), and a 25 percent income tax for those above the $100,000 threshold. He claims that his proposal would reduce tax return filings by 80 percent to 90 percent. Failing that, Graetz proposes repeal of the regular tax because by 2008, the AMT will produce more revenue than the regular tax while requiring filing of 40 million fewer tax returns. That would bring far more simplification and fairness than the Linder tax and introduce a major new revenue source. It might also be an invitation to a far higher tax burden that could more simply be generated through the existing income tax mechanism.17

The income tax is one of the most flexible and useful taxes. It can be used as a weapon against inflation or to redistribute wealth. Adjusting rates and the taxable base at the high end influences savings and investment. Those same adjustments at the low end influence consumption. It has been overused to effect social and economic policies, another proof of its utility. No other single tax serves so many functions.

The revenue stream from the income tax is sufficiently reliable, without inducing inflation, to leverage debt. It was the revenue stream from income taxes that enabled the United States to finance the Civil War, World War I, and World War II, and convinced lenders that our government was creditworthy so that it could borrow many times the tax base. That still holds true today.

The Challenge

There will be fierce opposition to reducing participation in the income tax. Many will promote the old argument of William Bourke Cockran that the poor must participate in every tax the government imposes or lose the right of participation. The tax preparation industry will oppose, arguing that the current system works. (No, it's broken. That's why we have a tax reform commission.) The real estate industry will predict a collapse. Charities will predict a humanitarian disaster. Insurance companies are already squawking that they might lose half their products without tax incentives. A friend at the IRS volunteer income tax assistance program argued with me that the poor shouldn't be deprived of participation in the income tax.

The wealthy will oppose being singled out for income tax. The poor will fear loss of the EITC (even if unfounded). Most arguments will be speculative. Congress will fear loss of influence as the majority of the population loses immediate concern for an income tax that no longer reaches them. (Not to mention the effect on campaign fundraising.)

The benefits from concentrating on just the 32 percent of the population that yields the substantial revenue on which our nation depends includes reduced compliance costs. That would save consumers and businesses billions of dollars annually. Much complexity stems from arranging fairness for the majority 68 percent. Reducing income tax filings by 89 million would vastly simplify the IRS computer modernization program, the second high-risk area identified by the GAO.

We could simplify tax calculations. It has become increasingly difficult to manually verify a computer tax calculation. There are three interacting baskets of income: (1) regular income tax at 10 percent, 15 percent, 25 percent, 28 percent, 33 percent, and 35 percent, (2) alternative minimum income tax at 26 percent and 28 percent, and (3) capital gains tax at 5 percent, 15 percent, 25 percent, and 28 percent on net long-term capital gains in excess of net short-term capital losses, interacting with the ordinary rates and the AMT, plus all the phaseouts. Those calculations precede the tax credits and additional taxes that must also be computed to arrive at the proper tax liability.

Twenty-five years ago I would review returns for missed deductions or elections or failure to use income averaging. Today the big errors are often buried in complex computer calculations of AMT adjustments that few preparers manually verify. Those errors are as likely to favor the government as the taxpayer.

In making its individual income tax recommendations, the tax reform commission should (1) drop the filing requirement for tens of millions of unnecessary tax returns, (2) reduce and restrict the nonrevenue functions of the IRS, (3) rationalize the tax burden we place on the spending class and the incentives we provide to the saving class, and (4) improve progressivity of our tax structure.

Graetz correctly points out that "[t]he fundamental problem is that the IRS is being asked to do too much." Getting the IRS to do less involves dramatically reducing the number of tax returns that are filed. The tax reform commission will fail if it does not get rid of unnecessary returns by whatever means it decides to propose. Simplifying taxes is easy. Just get rid of 89 million unnecessary income tax returns.


FOOTNOTES

1 Randolph E. Paul, Taxation for Prosperity (Indianapolis: Bobs-Merrill Company, 1947), p. 261. Paul was a prominent tax lawyer, founder of Paul, Weiss, Rifkind, Wharton, and Garrison, and author of many tax books, including coauthoring the original Mertens Law of Federal Income Taxation. He was Treasury general counsel during World War II and was the one who turned the income tax into a mass tax. See http://www.taxhistory.org/thp/readings.nsf/ .

2 Michael Graetz, "100 Million Unnecessary Returns: A Fresh Start for the U.S. Tax System," 112 Yale Law Journal 261 (November 2002).

3 Scott Hodge, "44 Million Will File Tax Returns But Pay Nothing," Tax Foundation's Tax Features, March/April 2004, p. 1. Updated article at http://www.taxfoundation.org/publications/show/542.html.

4 William Bourke Cockran. 53-2 Cong. Rec. vol. 26, Appendix, pp. 462-469 (Jan. 30, 1894) at 464-465.

5 William Jennings Bryan. 53-2 Cong. Rec. vol. 26, pp. 1655-1658 (Jan. 30, 1894) at 1656.

6 Jordan A. Schwarz, "John Nance Garner and the Sales Tax Rebellion of 1932," Journal of Southern History, May 1964, pp. 162-180. Garner's poor handling of the sales tax issue is one reason Roosevelt defeated him for the 1932 Democratic presidential nomination. Garner had to settle for vice president.

7 Randolph Paul, Taxation in the United States (Boston: Little, Brown, and Company, 1954), pp. 326-349. Paul wrote that a comprehensive study on a federal retail sales tax was inserted into the printed record of the Ways and Means Committee hearings in July 1943. I have not checked the Congressional Record, but the following memo may be the study he was referring to: "Considerations Respecting a Federal Retail Sales Tax," Staff Memo, Division of Tax Research, U.S. Treasury Department, Aug. 26, 1943, reproduced at http://www.taxhistory.org/Civilization/Documents/ Sales/HST29010/sales.htm.

8 Paul, supra note 1, at 149-154, 186.

9 John F. Witte, The Politics and Development of the Federal Income Tax (Madison, WI: University of Wisconsin Press, 1985), pp. 147-148.

10 U.S. Census Bureau, "Historical Income Tables -- Table F-8. Size of Family by Median and Mean Income: 1947 to 2001, Families With Four People," see http://www.census.gov/hhes/income/histinc/f08.html.

11 "High-Risk Series, an Update," U.S. Government Accountability Office, GAO-05-207 (January 2005), pp. 37- 38; "Internal Revenue Service, Recommendations to Improve Financial Operational Management," U.S. General Accounting Office, GAO-01-42 (November 2000); "Internal Revenue Service, Status of Recommendations From Financial Audits and Related Financial Management Reports," U.S. Government Accountability Office, GAO- 05-393 (April 2005), p. 21.

12 Janet Spragens and Nancy Abramowitz, "Low-Income Taxpayers and the Modernized IRS: A View From the Trenches," Tax Notes, June 13, 2005, p. 1407; Alan Berube, Anne Kim, Benjamin Forman, and Megan Burns, "The Price of Paying Taxes: How Tax Preparation and Refund Loan Fees Erode the Benefits of the EITC," the Brookings Institution and Progressive Policy Institute Survey Series (May 2002); see "Low Income Taxpayer Protection Act of 2005," H.R. 894 (2005), section 4(a)(1)(B), or search at http://thomas.loc.gov.

13 "Tax Loans: Quick Cash, Steep Price," Atlanta Journal-Constitution, April 3, 2005, p. D1; David Cay Johnston, "Tax Credit Is Financial Bonanza for 2 Big Tax Preparers," New York Times, May 21, 2002, p. C1.

14 EITC and other welfare programs offset much regressivity for low-income taxpayers. For a full discussion of this complex subject, see C. Eugene Steuerle and Jon M. Bakija, Retooling Social Security for the 21st Century, Right & Wrong Approaches to Reform (Washington, D.C.: Urban Institute Press, 1994).

15 Taxable income in 2002 totaled $4.1 trillion. Replacing $72 billion lost from exempting almost $900 billion of taxable income of the 68 percent majority requires raising rates on the 32 percent that remain by just 2 percent. The same $72 billion could be raised with an 8 percent flat withholding tax on lower incomes.

16 Linder has coauthored The Fair Tax Book: Saying Goodbye to the Income Tax and the IRS, with radio talk show host Neal Boortz. Though he wrote this book on tax policy, Boortz seems never to have heard of Tax Analysts before reading that he's been awarded "this year's prize for Worst Idea in a Serious Public Policy Debate." This ignorant tax book is a bestseller. http://www.taxhistory.org, click on "Readings in Tax History," then "Fair Tax, Bad Tax" (May 26, 2005).

17 Graetz, supra note 2. Sheryl Stratton, "Tax Lawyers Critique Graetz Reform Plan at Judicial Conference," Tax Notes, May 2, 2005, p. 560.

END OF FOOTNOTES

Jay Starkman is a sole practitioner in Atlanta. This article was originally published in Tax Notes, August 15, 2005.  (c)2005  Tax Analysts.

--------------------------------------

Created: August 23, 2005; Last updated: March 25, 2013